sexta-feira, 25 de maio de 2012

história econômica

Working Paper 04-66 Dpto. de Historia Económica e Instituciones Economic History and Institutions Series 04 Universidad Carlos III de Madrid December 2004 Calle Madrid 126 28903 Getafe (Spain) WHEN DID LATIN AMERICA FALL BEHIND?. EVIDENCE FROM LONG-RUN INTERNATIONAL INEQUALITY* Leandro Prados de la Escosura+ Abstract_______________________________________________________________ When did Latin America fall behind?. Has the gap between developed countries and Latin America widened over time?. This paper addresses these recurrent questions with the tools provided by the inequality literature. Long-run inter-country inequality is assessed in terms of real (purchasing power-adjusted) GDP per head and of an ‘improved’ human development index as an indicator of welfare for present-day OECD and Latin America. A long term rise in income inequality is observed for this sample of countries with the deepening gap between OECD and Latin America as its main determinant. Contrary to a widespread view, in terms of income, Latin America fell behind in the late twentieth century. Inequality in terms of human development declined over time, but the gap between OECD and Latin America remained largely unchanged. JEL classification: N30, N36, I31 Key words: Inequality, Retardation, Real Income, Human Development, Latin America * This essay was presented at the 2004 Inter-American Seminar on Economics sponsored by the National Bureau of Economic Research and El Colegio de Mexico in México, D.F.. I am grateful to its participants, and especially to my discussant Luis Felipe López Calva, for their remarks and suggestions. Useful comments by Pablo Astorga and Joan Rosés are acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies. + Prados de la Escosura, Dpto de Historia Económica e Instituciones. Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. E-mail: leandro.prados.delaescosura@uc3m.es 2 I. Introduction When did Latin America fall behind?, Has the gap between the developed countries, the Core, and Latin America, the Periphery, widened over time? are recurrent questions among economic historians. The idea of long run relative decline since independence has been favored in the literature (see, for example, Victor Bulmer-Thomas (1994: 410)), while it is widely accepted that the origins of modern Latin American retardation are located in the nineteenth century (John Coatsworth, 1993, and Stephen Haber, 1997). Coatsworth (1998) emphasizes that Latin America fell behind between 1700 and 1900, while the gap with the US remained unchanged during the twentieth century. The evidence on comparative real product per head assembled by Pablo Astorga and Valpy Fitzgerald (1998: 353) lends support to this view1. Explanatory hypotheses for the early failure of Latin America emphasize the radically different evolution of Anglo and Latin Americas reflected the imposition of distinct metropolitan institutions on each colony (North, 1990). The break with the metropolis destroyed institutions that provided credible commitments to rights and property within the Spanish empire and, as a result, widespread turmoil, violence and political instability took place after independence with the consequence of sluggish economic growth (North, Summerhill and Weingast, 2000). Initial inequality of wealth, human capital and political power conditioned institutional design and, thus, poor performance in Latin America relative to the US (Engerman and Sokoloff, 1997). Views from the Dependencia school concur. The failure to achieve sustained and balanced growth over the nineteenth-century was a result of the persistence of colonial heritage in the new republics (Stanley and Barbara Stein, 1970)2. Dependentists saw the opening to the international economy as a cause of increasing inequality across and within countries, stressing the role of the terms of trade in Latin American retardation by shifting resources to primary production (Hans Singer, 1950) and by provoking immiserizing growth (Raúl Prebisch, 1950). As interpretations of early backwardness rest on a long-run comparison between Latin America and the US it must be stressed that most countries, including those of Western Europe, fell behind over the nineteenth century when measured by American standards. Moreover, the common claim that Latin America’s relative position to the U.S. 1 In a recent paper, however, Astorga, Bergés and Fitzgerald (2004) stress that per capita income for a sample of thirteen countries diverged from the US in the second half of the twentieth century. 2 The Steins (1970: 128) stress, however, US exceptionalism, “the existence of a huge, under-populated virgin land of extraordinary resource endowment directly facing Europe and enjoying a climate comparable to that of Europe represented a potentiality for development which existed nowhere else in the New World”. 3 remained mostly unaltered during the twentieth century is at odds with the catching up experience in large areas of the Periphery (Southern and Eastern Europe, Southeast Asia) where the gap with the U.S. in terms of income per head was significantly reduced after 1950. The US seems, therefore, a questionable yardstick to assess Latin America’s economic performance (Prados de la Escosura, 2004b). Whether Latin America fell behind in the late twentieth century or in the early nineteenth century has important consequences for the ongoing debate on the causes of Latin America’s retardation. If Latin America’s backwardness has its origins in the decades following independence the institutional and factor endowment discrepancies with the US and Western Europe are relevant to its explanation. If, however, retardation occurred in the late twentieth century, institutional and factor endowment differences between Latin and British Americas during the colonial period and the post-independence epoch would become secondary to the exploration of what went wrong in Latin America during the phase of widespread catching up to the developed countries in regions of the Periphery (Southern Europe, East Asia)3. My purpose in this paper is to re-assess the timing of Latin America’s retardation, first, by using a more representative comparator such as a group of countries included today under the OECD acronym, and second, by resorting to the tools employed in the inequality literature4. No systematic attempt has been made to assess international inequality over the long run except for François Bourguignon and Christian Morrisson (2002) and Peter Lindert and Jeffrey Williamson (2003) recent contributions5. Interestingly, Bourguignon and Morrison (2002: 738) did not discuss the case of Latin America “because its economic growth over the last two centuries has roughly coincided with the world average”. Inferences on long-run trends in inequality rest almost exclusively on GDP per head, at odds with the increasing challenge to GDP per head as a measure of welfare6. Different socio-economic indicators have been explored as an alternative to GDP per head amid 3 Cf. Alan Taylor (1998) for an exploration of the distortions underlying Latin America’s distinctive behavior. 4 I describe ‘OECD’, for short, a sample of today’s advanced nations from Europe, the so called ‘areas of new settlement’ or Maddison’s ‘European offshoots’ (Australia, Canada, and New Zealand), the U.S.A. and Japan. 5 The prevailing view in the inequality literature is a growing disparity between rich and poor nations over the last two centuries, in which between-country inequality appears as the main determinant, although this view does not seem to hold for the late twentieth century. 6 Income per head as a welfare indicator has been recurrently questioned since the spread of national accounts half a century ago (United Nations, 1954; Partha Dasgupta, 1993; Stanley Engerman, 1997), in spite of its advantage as a synthetic index and the observed association between economic growth and welfare (W.A. Lewis, 1955; Wilfred Beckerman, 1993). 4 strong criticism7. The United Nations Development Program’s Human Development Index, published annually since 1990, is the latest addition. In this paper long-run trends in inter-country inequality are computed both for real income per head (that is, purchasing power adjusted GDP per head), and for an amended, ‘improved’ index of human development. Among the main findings of the paper can be highlighted a long term rise in real per capita income inequality, that is mainly determined by the widening gap between OECD and Latin America. This result leads to the conclusion that contrary to a widespread belief, in terms of per capita income, Latin America fell behind during the late twentieth century. This finding is not confirmed, however, in terms of human development for which preliminary results suggest a drop in inter-country inequality over the long run. Yet, a large gap between OECD and Latin America still remained in 1990. The paper is organize as follows: Section II discusses the indicators used to assess historical trends in economic inequality and presents new measures of long-run international inequality for OECD and Latin American GDP per head that can be, then, decomposed into the underlying changes in within and across regions’ inequality. In section III an alternative welfare indicator to the conventional UNDP’s index of human development is offered, from which new decomposable measures of long-run international inequality are derived. In the concluding section the issue of when did Latin America fall behind is reconsidered. II. Long-Run Inequality in Real Income Real income data In international comparisons, dissatisfaction with nominal income (that is, GDP per head in national currency converted into a common currency using the trading exchange rate) has led to an almost generalized use of real income (the conversion into a common currency is carried out with a purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rate)8. Unfortunately, the construction of PPP converters involves high costs in terms of time and resources. Only PPPs for a restricted country sample that does not include any of Latin 7 Among them the Basic Needs Approach and the Physical Index of Quality of Life (PIQL). Cf. Irma Adelman and Cynthia Morris, 1967; Beckerman, 1966; Beckerman and Bacon, 1966; Eva Ehrlich, 1969; Heston, 1973; Hicks and Streeten, 1979; Larson and Wilford, 1979; M.D. Morris, 1979; Paul Streeten et al., 1981; McGranahan et al., 1985; Rati Ram, 1982. 8 Empirical evidence gathered in recent years strongly rejects the conventional results obtained through the trading exchange rate converter (Summers and Heston, 1991; Bart van Ark, 1993). Trading exchange rates only reflect the purchasing power of goods traded internationally, and are influenced by capital movements, exchange controls and speculation (Maddison, 1995: 162). In other words, foreign exchange rates do not measure relative price levels and do not move with them overtime (Sultan Ahmad, 1998). 5 America have been constructed for earlier periods, and most of them for output components9. An indirect method to derive historical estimates of real income levels for a large sample of countries is the backward projection of PPP-adjusted GDP per capita for a recent benchmark with volume indices (or growth rates) of product per head derived from national accounts data10. It is worth noting that fixed-base real (PPP-adjusted) product data represent a most convenient alternative to carrying out painstaking direct comparisons across space and time and have the presentation advantage that their growth rates are identical to those calculated from national accounts11. Alas, a distant PPP benchmark introduces distortions in inter-temporal comparisons since its validity depends on how stable the basket of goods and services used to construct the original PPP converters remains over time. As growth occurs over time the composition of output, consumption and relative prices all vary, and the economic meaning of comparing real product per head based upon remote PPPs becomes entirely questionable. Hence, using a single PPP benchmark for long-run comparisons implies a hardly realistic assumption: that no changes in relative prices (and, hence, no technological change) takes place over time. Since PPP exchange rates were not computed directly for Latin American countries in 1990 (Maddison, 1995, 2001), I have resorted to a set of own-country weights (Paasche) PPP direct computations by Economic Commission for Latin America [ECLA] for 1960 (Braithwaite, 1968; ECLA, 1968) never used before in historical studies that provides a wider spatial coverage12. It is worth noticing that the frequently used 1970 benchmark, originally published by CEPAL [the Spanish acronym of ECLA] (1978) is just a projection of the 1960 benchmark levels with each Latin American country’s inflation differential with 9 In addition to O’Brien and Keyder (1978) and Fremdling (1991) PPP computations for commodity output, there are sectoral PPP estimates: for agriculture, van Zanden (1991) and O’Brien and Prados de la Escosura (1992), and for manufacturing, Broadberry and Fremdling (1990), Broadberry (1994, 1997), Burger (1997) and Dormois and Bardini (1995). Exceptionally, Williamson (1995) used an income approach. Recently, Ward and Devereux (2003a, 2003b) have accepted the challenge to build direct PPP estimates from the expenditure side for twelve western economies at five benchmarks (1872, 1884, 1905, 1930, and 1950). 10 Maddison (2003) 1990 Geary-Khamis dollar estimates provide the best example. 11 A significant strand of the literature defends the view defends that the best estimates of growth rates are those obtained from national accounts (Bhagwati and Hansen (1973); Isenman (1980); Kravis and Lipsey (1991); Maddison (1991, 1995)) on the grounds that “using domestic prices to measure growth rates is more reliable, because those prices characterize the trade offs faced by the decision making agents”(Nuxoll (1994)). Kravis and Lipsey (1991:458) argued that growth rates derived from domestic prices were preferable because of the basket of goods used “reflected the preferences of purchasers of final product in one of the years being compared”. 12 The commodity basket included 261 consumption goods and 113 investment goods for capital cities in nineteen Latin American countries and the US (Houston and Los Angeles). Prices were collected in 1960/62. Quantity expenditure weights for a Latin American average and the US in 1960 were used (ECLA, 1968; Braithwaite, 1968). PPPs in ECLA (1960) appear, thus, to be superior in country coverage but not in commodity coverage to ECIEL benchmark estimates for 1970 and 1975 (Salazar-Carrillo, 1983; Salazar- Carrillo and Tirado de Alonso, 1988; Salazar-Carrillo and Prasada Rao, 1988). 6 the USA13. Alternatively, Geary-Khamis PPPs derived by the UN’s International Comparisons Project [ICP] could have been used for most Latin American countries in 1980 (and, for all, in 1996). The choice of the 1960 benchmark obeys to two reasons: a) the possibility of employing GDP volume series expressed in US relative prices (derived with Paasche PPPs) that facilitated the comparison with available OECD countries’ real (PPPadjusted) income per head expressed in US relative prices (Prados de la Escosura, 2000) and b) that, in absence of current price PPP-adjusted GDP levels, real income at 1960 US prices provide a intermediate year for the time span considered and it is, hence, preferable to the use of a benchmark year for the end of the twentieth century14. A set of real product per head estimates, that includes Europe, the New World and Japan, has been constructed at 1960 US relative prices by projecting backwards with volume indices the ECLA (1968) benchmark for Latin America and my own one (Prados de la Escosura, 2000) for OECD countries15. Graph 1 presents population-weighted averages of per capita incomes in OECD and Latin America16. It can be noticed that Latin America grew at roughly the same pace as the OECD average between 1850 and 1870 and above the average rate of growth in OECD countries between 1870 and 1913 (except when the three country sample, LA3, is considered), but slightly below it during the Interwar years and way below it after 1950 (and especially after 1980). The relative position of Latin America in terms of OECD GDP per head presents a wide U-shape for all country samples, except for LA3 (Graph 2). The improvement in Latin American relative income per capita from the late nineteenth century up to 1913 gave way, after stabilizing during the Interwar years, to a sharp decline in the second half of the twentieth century. A similar exercise comparing Latin America to the Anglo-Saxon New World (Canada, the USA, Australia and New Zealand), or to the richest top OECD countries, casts almost identical results. However, when the comparison is carried out since 1850, for only three Latin American countries, the relative position of Latin America varies significantly, and two phases can be clearly depicted: a relative decline up to 1900, followed by a tendency to stabilize up to 1980. This long-run picture of Latin America based on a very limited country sample fits, nonetheless, the widespread perception of the nineteenth century as an 13 Astorga and Fitzgerald (1998), for example, use the CEPAL’s 1970 projected benchmark. 14 I am preparing new short-cut current price estimates of real income (at US relative prices) for Latin America that will be used in a next version of the paper. 15 The sources for volume indices of GDP per head are provided in Appendix C. 16 The number of countries included in each sample figures after the region’s name, that is, LA6 means that six countries are included in this Latin American (LA) sample. 7 epoch of retardation in which Latin America fell behind. If the exercise is replicated for Latin America vis-à-vis the Anglo-Saxon New World (Australia, New Zealand, Canada, and the US), a similar pattern appears (Graph 2b). It is clear that a view that rests on such a reduced and biased country sample and that does not coincide with the robust view of Latin America’s relative performance that derives from samples which include six or more countries, lacks significance. And, what about the decades between independence and midnineteenth century?. Latin America probably grew at a slower pace between 1820 and 1850 than thereafter, though lack of data prevents to carrying out a similar exercise to that for the post-1850 era. It can be said, however, that countries behave quite differently across Latin America: while Mexico seems to have experienced a decline in per capita income (Coatsworth, 1989; Salvucci, 1997), and that was probably also the case of Peru (Quiroz, 1993), Brazil might have experienced a mild increase in per capita income (Leff, 1982), while in Cuba income per head apparently grew until 1860 (Fraile, Salvucci and Salvucci, 1993); Chile (Díaz et al, 1998), Venezuela (Baptista, 1997), most probably Argentina (Newland, 1998; Newland and Poulson, 1998) and, perhaps, Colombia (Jaramillo et al, 2001) improved their real income per head17. Thus, jumping to a definitive conclusion about an early, post-independence decline in Latin America is premature. Moreover, retardation could only be claimed if the comparator is reduced to a handful of North- Western European countries that experienced sustained per capita income growth prior to 1850 (Table A.1). The high variance of growth rates of GDP per capita in Latin America is worth highlighting after 1870 (Graph 3). Argentina, Chile and Mexico income per head grew above Latin American and OECD averages between 1870 and 1913, Brazil, Colombia, Peru, and Venezuela did it over 1913-1938, but none did it after 1950 (although Brazil, Colombia, and Mexico grew above the Latin American average). As countries starting from lower income levels appear to have grown faster over the long run a pattern of convergence among Latin American nations is observed while they tend to diverge from the OECD average incomes (Graph 4). To sum up, it appears that over the period considered that spans over two phases of globalization and one of de-globalization, Latin America does not seem to have fallen behind until the late twentieth century. Such a finding is in contradiction with conventional assessments that locates Latin American retardation in the nineteenth century. 17 In the case of Chile, Diaz et al. (1998) figures, suggest that real output per head grew at 1.4 percent between 1820 and 1850, while Baptista (1997) estimates point to an annual compound rate of 2.2 percent for real income per head between 1831/35 and 1851/55. As regards Mexico, an annual decline in GDP per capita of -0.5 percent for 1800-1845 is suggested by Coatsworth, (1989). 8 Real income inequality A more rigorous assessment of income inequality in Latin America and OECD is obtained with the comprehensive measures provided by entropy decomposable indices. Was inequality significantly larger for the international country sample that includes Latin America and OECD countries in 1990 than in 1870?, Were there different phases in inequality?, Was there, as suggested by Bourguignon and Morrison (2002), a sustained rise in inequality up to 1950 that tended to stabilize thereafter?, Did the gap between OECD (the Core) and Latin America (the Periphery) contribute to the increase in long-term inequality?, are pressing questions to which I will try to respond. All measures of inequality among OECD and Latin America’s countries are simultaneously provided for alternative country samples covering 1870-1990, 1913-1990, 1929-1990, and 1950-1990, respectively, with the more comprehensive samples covering a shorter time span, that allow to test the sensitivity of the results to changes in the sample’s composition18. Only countries for which data on GDP actually exists are comprised in the sample19. Needless to say, the quality and coverage of the estimates show a large variance and usually fall as one goes back in time20. Weighted measures of inequality (population-weighted, MLD, and incomeweighted, Theil) for the four country samples of ‘OECD’ and Latin American countries are presented in Table 121. MLDy = Σ pi ln (pi/yi) [4] Theily = Σ yi ln (yi/pi) [5], with pi and yi representing the shares of country i in total (OECD and Latin America) population and GDP. In addition to inequality levels, yearly rates of inequality reduction, in other words, the speed at which inequality falls (positive sign) or rises (negative sign), are shown at the bottom of each table. A rise in per capita income inequality over the long run is observed for the Latin America and OECD sample (Graph 5)22. The increase in inequality is more intense when 18 The countries included for real income inequality estimates are listed in Appendix A. 19 And no ‘heroic’ assumptions are introduced in an attempt to widen the geographical coverage of the sample. 20 But no ‘imaginative’ solutions for missing countries, such as assuming identical levels of income or growth rates to their neighbors, are employed. Bourguignon and Morrison (2002) provide a good example of this: real income for missing Eastern European and non-European countries in the nineteenth century, for example, was interpolated with the growth rates of ‘comparable neighboring countries’. Maddison (1995, 2001) also used this extrapolation procedure to expand his country’s coverage. 21 Mean Logarithmic Deviation (MLD) is also known as Bourgignon’s L and Theil’s population weighted index. Theil is short for Theil’s income weighted index of inequality. Population shares in columns 4 and 5 provides an idea of each sample’s coverage of Latin American countries. 9 measured with the MLD index, that gives more weight to changes at the bottom of the distribution. In addition, the wider the country coverage of the indices, the deeper inequality. A closer look reveals that, when measured with the MLD index, a moderate increase in inequality took place between 1890 and 1929. After a decline during the Depression years, the disruption brought about by World War II provoked a dramatic upsurge in inequality. Although inequality fell during the nineteen fifties, its level remained higher and relatively stable (and even increased slightly when the MLD index is used) until 1980, when a major rise occurred. The years between 1870 and 1990 witnessed population and GDP growth to proceed with different intensity across countries. To what extent did the variance in their rates of growth have an impact on income inequality?. I have simulated the yearly rates at which, other things being equal, inequality would have fallen if all countries in the sample had enjoyed identical population (or per capita income) growth. The simulation exercise has been carried out for each of the three epochs in which the long century studied has been conventionally divided: the early phase of globalization of the late nineteenth century, the Interwar years of globalization backlash, and the post-World War II era of growth and globalization. The actual way of carrying out the simulation was to compute weighted inequality measures in which, ceteris paribus, population (or per capita income) remained unchanged over each epoch. This amounts to allocate identical growth rates to population (or per capita income) for all countries in the sample. Table 2 offers the results of simulating what would have happened in our country sample had the variance of population (or income) growth been zero. They suggest that, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century, differences in demographic expansion prevented an increase in inequality while, in the interwar, population and GDP growth acted as a counterbalance forces, and while income growth differentials provoked its decline, the variance in population growth slowed down the fall in inequality. Again, in the post-1950 years population growth variance was an obstacle to the reduction in inequality. It can be argued, therefore, that differentials in population growth, mostly stemming from Latin America’s late demographic transition, represented an obstacle to reduce inequality in the ‘OECD’ and Latin America country sample during the ‘short’ twentieth century (1913- 1990). Such a finding is in conflict with Bourguignon and Morrison (2002) contention that population growth rates are not associated with significant changes in world income distribution. 22 Alternative MLD and Theil indices are computed for country samples starting at different dates, thus, MLD1870 means that the computed MLD index covers from 1870 to 1990. 10 Another way to look at inequality trends is to decompose OECD and Latin America weighted inequality into the share attributable to distribution changes within each region and the share that stems from differences amongst regions. I have followed Theil (1979, 1989) in decomposing aggregate inequality into within-regions and between-regions inequality. ‘Within-regions’ inequality is obtained by adding up the results of weighting each region’s inequality measure (either MLD or Theil) by its population (income) share. ‘Between-regions’ inequality is, then, obtained as the difference between total (OECD and Latin America) inequality and the computed ‘within-regions’ inequality. In Graphs 6A and 6B it is noticeable that ‘between-regions’ inequality, that is, between ‘OECD’ and Latin America, experienced a sustained rise since the 1920s, after the flat trend prior to World War I, while a declining trend (but for the post-World War II) is exhibited in ‘within-regions’ inequality. The deepening gap between ‘OECD’ and Latin America constitutes, hence, the main element underlying the observed increase in overall inequality (Graph 5). When inequality within each region is examined, two clear trends emerged in Latin America: a steep rise prior to 1914, followed by a sustained decline over the ‘short’ twentieth century (1914-1990), with the result of lower inequality levels than in the late nineteenth century (Graphs 7A and 7B). The long-run fall in twentieth century inequality is, no doubt, conditioned by Argentine’s collapse in its international position. OECD exhibits a sustained decline in inequality only interrupted by World War II and its aftermath. To sum up, the long-run increase in inequality is mainly due to the widening gap between average incomes between OECD and Latin America that peaked in the late twentieth century. It is then when Latin America appears to have fallen behind. III. Long-Run Inequality in Human Development Income per head is just one dimension of material well-being and social scientists have been looking at inequality of welfare indicators. Increasing levels of inequality in lifetime income, resulting from combining trends in income with those in life expectancy, peaked in 1950 to stabilize and, even, to converge, thereafter, according to Bourguignon and Morrison (2002). The view that standards of living converged in the late twentieth century has been disputed by Hobijn and Franses (2001) on the basis of Kakwani (1993) ‘achievement indices23. 23 Hobijn and Franses (2001) weight countries by their size (population or income), in contrast to the inequality literature (but along the convergence literature). 11 In this section of the paper inequality is measured in terms of an improved version of the UNDP’s human development index. The Human Development Index The Human Development Index [HDI] complements more conventional measures of welfare such as per capita income or consumption adding a new dimension to our knowledge of material progress over time24. As a synthetic measure of Human Development, the HDI captures a country’s achievements in longevity, knowledge and living standards through various indices: the relative achievement in life expectancy at birth, in education and in “all dimensions of human development not reflected in a long and healthy life and in knowledge” for which (the logarithm of) per capita GDP is a surrogate (UNDP, 2001: 240). The rationale for using the log of per capita income, that implies diminishing marginal utility of income, is that a decent standard of living does not require unlimited income25. Indices for each dimension are computed according to the following formula, Dimension Index = (x - Mo) / (M - Mo), [1] where x is the observed value of a given dimension of welfare, and Mo and M represent the maximum and minimum values, or goalposts. Goalposts representing levels not reached yet and below the present’s lowest level, respectively, have been chosen for each indicator in UNDP’s HDI in order to make comparisons over time feasible. For life expectancy at birth the maximum and the minimum values are established at 85 and 25 years, respectively. For education, the maximum and minimum are 100 and 0. The education index combines adult literacy and gross enrolment (primary, secondary and tertiary), with two-thirds and one-third weights, respectively. In the case of per capita GDP, the maximum and minimum values are the logarithms of 40,000 and 100 dollars, respectively. The performance of each dimension ranges between 0 and 1. Then, the UNDP’s HDI is obtained as the unweighted arithmetic average of the three dimension indices. 24 Human Development was originally defined as “a process of enlarging people’s choices” that enables them “to lead a long and healthy life, to acquire knowledge and to have access to resources needed for a decent standard of living” (United Nations Development Programme [UNDP], 1990: 10). Human capability, the doctrinal basis for human development, focuses on “the ability of human beings to lead lives they have reasons to value and to enhance the substantive choices they have” (Sen, 1997), as opposed to the concept of human capital, that augments production possibilities through skills and knowledge. For historical estimates, cf. Crafts (1997, 2002). 25 This transformation of income introduced in 1999, had already been recommended by Sagar and Najam (1998: 254). Unhappiness with the earlier formula is discussed, among others, by Gormley (1995). Astorga, Berges and Fitgerald (2004) depict the use of the marginal utility notion as arbitrary. 12 The reactions to non-conventional indicators of well-being have always been critical as regards their economic meaning, lack of welfare economic foundations and method of computation (Srinivassan, 1994; Dowrick, Dunlop and Quiggin 2003). The choice of HDI’s components and its combination into a single index has provoked an endless debate. Main issues are whether HDI components (longevity, education and income) provide different insights of welfare or are just redundant (McGillivray, 1991). If they capture different welfare dimensions, then, should equal and fixed weights be allocated to each component of human development over time? 26. And is an arithmetic average the right procedure to combine the three dimensions into the HDI?. Finally, is a linear transformation the best way to obtain non-income dimensions of human development from original values of education and life expectancy? 27. I have constructed a new index of human development that takes into account assessments of the UNDP’s HDI and suggestions for its improvement28. I have followed Kakwani’s axiomatic approach to transform the original values of non-income variables into their human development dimensions. Kakwani constructed a normalized index from an achievement function in which an increase in the standard of living of a country at a higher level implies a greater achievement than had it been the case if it took place at a lower level (Kakwani, 1993: 308)29. The proposed achievement function is, following Atkinson (1970), f (x, Mo, M) = ((M - Mo)1-ε – (M – x)1-ε) / ((M - Mo)1-ε), for 0 <ε <1 [2] where, x is an indicator of a country’s standard of living, and M and Mo are the maximum and minimum values, respectively. The achievement function is a convex function of x, and it is equal to 0, if x = Mo, and equal to 1, if x = M, ranging, then, between 0 and 1. In the case favored by Kakwani’s axiomatic approach, ε takes a value of 1, turning into, f (x, Mo, M) = (log (M - Mo) – log (M – x)) / (log (M - Mo)), [3] where log stands for the natural logarithm. 26 Cf. Kakwani (1993), Aturupane, Glewwe and Isenman (1994) and Dasgupta and Weale (1992). 27 An additional worry derives from the fact that the HDI combines stock and flows variables (Aturupane, Glewwe and Isenman, 1994: 246). 28 Prados de la Escosura (2004a). I have computed two sets of human development indices: the conventional UNDP HDI and the ‘improved’ HDI. The ‘improved’ HDI represents an alternative to conventional UNHDI that, in my view, fits better the Human Development Reports’ approach as this usually highlights the differences between Core and Periphery countries. 29 For example, in the case of longevity, “a further increase must be regarded as a greater achievement than an equal increase at lower levels of longevity, f (x, Mo, M) must be a convex function of x, i.e., the achievement must increase at a faster rate than the longevity” (Kakwani, 1993: 313). 13 It should be noticed that the UNDP’s HDI represents a particular case in which ε = 0, yielding expression [1] for each social dimension of the index30. In the new, ‘improved’ HDI [IHDI], while social dimensions are derived with a convex achievement function (that is, using expression [3]), income’s diminishing returns transformation is maintained (and, consequently, the logarithmic transformation of per capita income is employed). In addition, a geometric average has been employed to combine its three main dimensions (longevity, knowledge, and income) into the new IHDI31. A minor additional change has been introduced in the goalposts for life expectancy at birth, where 80 years has been taken as its maximum and 20 years as its minimum. The reason for reducing them is that goalposts represent levels above and below the highest and lowest exhibit by the group of countries and, in our sample, the maximum and minimum values for life expectancy, are 78.8 and 24, respectively32. The ‘improved’ human development indices have been computed with the real (PPP-adjusted) GDP per capita at 1960 US relative prices used in the income inequality estimates. Lack of data for Latin America forced me to compute one of the HDI attributes, education attainment, with literacy instead of combining literacy (2/3) and primary, secondary and tertiary enrolment (1/3). As a result the inequality estimates are downward biased as one moves close to the present since literacy rates have become universal, in particular, for ‘OECD’ countries33. Moreover, for the same reasons neglecting enrolment rates will possibly bias upwards the human development index for Latin America in the late twentieth century. Population-weighted average levels of human development in OECD and Latin America are offered in Graph 8. Human development in Latin America is systematically lower than those in the OECD countries (Table A.2). Nonetheless, human development improved in Latin America faster than in the OECD and, consequently, the gap between the two regions fell in the long run (Graph 9), in clear contrast with Latin American relative 30 This particular case does not satisfy, however, one of the axioms of the achievement index defined by Kakwani: that the index should give greater weight to the improvement of a country which has higher level for each social indicator. 31 It should be bear in mind that a geometric average of the index’s components has the advantage of reducing their substitutability significantly, somehow avoiding that an improvement in one attribute may offset a worsening in another, with a resulting neutral aggregate effect on the HDI. 32 Both Dasgupta (1990) and Kakwani (1993) used 80 years as the maximum goalpost for life expectancy at birth in present time developing countries. Life expectancy in some late nineteenth century Latin American countries was less than 25 years (Astorga and Fitzgerald, 1998). The sources of the social components of the human development index: life expectancy, literacy and enrolment are provided in Prados de la Escosura (2004). 33 In a next version of the paper, the education attainment measure will include literacy and enrolment rates. 14 performance in terms of per capita income (Graph 2). Two periods, 1890-1913 and 1938- 60 appear as the phases of more intense catching-up, with a weakening in the last decade, especially the 1980s. A high variance is observed in human development performance across Latin America (Graph 10). Argentina and Mexico experienced improvements in human development above Latin American average before 1913, while in the Interwar years Mexico and Venezuela took the lead. After World War II these countries were joined by Brazil, Colombia and Peru. Thus, countries with lower levels of human development exhibit more intense improvement with the result of a reduction in the dispersion of welfare across Latin America over time. Yet, the gap between countries in the Southern Cone and the rest was not negligible in 1990, with the former in middle level of human development and the latter in the lower level (Graph 11)34. HDI Inequality The same formulae used to measure income inequality have been employed, with ‘improved’ HDI and per capita income considered analogously, MLDh = Σ pi ln (pi/hi) [6] Theilh = Σ hi ln (hi/pi) [7], with pi and hi representing the shares of country i in total (‘OECD’) population and human development (HDI times population). Table 3 provides inequality estimates for ‘OECD’ and Latin America for the hundred years after 1890. In the long run, human development inequality, driven by literacy and life expectancy, fell, a result clearly at odds with the rise found for real income inequality. The steady fall in inequality that took place in the pre-World War I and the post- World War II years, the 1950s, in particular, account for it (Graph 12). It is worth noticing the discrepancies between the Theil index, that gives more weight to the upper part of the distribution, and the MLD index, that allocates more weight to the lower part. In terms of the Theil index inequality increased in the Interwar and in the 1980s,while it remained unchanged in terms of the MLD index. If we now decompose OECD and Latin America weighted inequality into the share attributable to distribution changes within each region and the share that stems from differences amongst regions, it appears that ‘within-regions’ inequality dominates the long run decline in observed (Graphs 13A and 13B). Inequality plummeted both within the 34 In UNDP standard classification, lower represents below 0.5, while middle, between 0.5 and 0.8. It should be borne in mind that in the improved HDI a country level tends to be below the one in the conventional UNDP, HDI 15 ‘OECD’ and within Latin America (Graphs 14A and 14B), but while a sustained fall occurred in the ‘OECD’, an upsurge of inequality up the Great Depression was followed in Latin America by a sharp contraction until 1960 that softened or stabilized thereafter depending on whether the MLD or the Theil index is used. In sum, while overall inequality fell significantly over the long run, the gap between OECD and Latin America only experienced a relatively moderate reduction since it tended to stabilize after 1960 (and even to reverse after 1980, according to the Theil index). IV. Concluding Remarks In this preliminary attempt to identify when did Latin America fall behind and how the gap between the Core (OECD) and the Periphery (Latin America) has evolved over time, some tentative results can be offered: A long term rise in real per capita income inequality for a partial sample of the world that includes Latin America and OECD countries is noticed. This finding contradicts the benign view of a rise in inequality up to the mid-twentieth century that stabilized thereafter proposed by Bourguignon and Morrison (2002). National differences in population growth, largely a consequence of the late demographic transition in Latin America, held up a fall in inequality during the ‘short’ twentieth century (1913-1990). The deepening gap between OECD and Latin America was the major factor beneath the observed increase. This result provides, at least, a tentative answer to the question of when did Latin America fall behind. Contrary to a widely held view, Latin America’s retardation vis-à-vis OECD countries appears to be a (late) twentieth century phenomenon35. Moreover, the decline that probably took place in the decades after independence seems hardly comparable to the dramatic fall that took place in Latin America’s relative position to the OECD in the late twentieth century. Aggregate inequality in human development fell in the long run, a result of relative achievements in education and life expectancy in Latin America, especially during the central decades of the twentieth century. Yet a large gap between the ‘OECD’ and Latin America did remain in 1990. 35 Of course, only the post-1850 era is analyzed here but similar results appear when the scope is widened both in time and regional coverage. Cf. Prados de la Escosura (2004b). 16 References Adelman, I. and C.T. Morris (1967), Society, Politics and Economic Development, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Ahmad, S. (1998), “International Comparisons of Incomes: Why Should One Bother Using PPP Conversion?”. PREM seminar Price and Purchasing Power Parities at the World Bank. Ark, B. van (1993), “The ICOP Approach. Its Implications and Applicability”. In A. Szirmai, B. van Ark and D. Pilat (Eds.), Explaining Economic Growth, Amsterdam: North Holland. Pp. 375-398. Astorga, P. and V. Fitzgerald (1998), “Statistical Appendix”, in R. Thorp, Progress, Poverty and Exclusion. An Economic History of Latin America in the 20th Century, Washington: Inter-American Development Bank, pp. 307-65. Astorga, P., A. R. Berges and V. Fitzgerald (2004), “The Standard of Living in Latin America During the Twenty Century”, University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History no 54. Atkinson, A.B. (1970), “On Measurement of Inequality”, Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244-63. Aturupane, H., P. Glewwe and P. Isenman (1994), “Poverty, Human Development, and Growth: An Emerging Consensus?”, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 84, 2: 244-9. Bakker, G.P. den, T.A. Huitker and C.A. van Bochove (1990), “The Dutch Economy 1921-1938: Revised Macroeconomic Data for the Interwar Period”. Review of Income and Wealth, 36, 187-206. Balke, N.S. and R.J. Gordon (1989), "The Estimation of Prewar Gross National Product: Methodology and New Evidence". Journal of Political Economy, 97, 38-92. Baptista, A. (1997), Bases cuantitativas de la economía venezolana 1830-1995, Caracas: Fundación Polar. Batista, D., C. Martins, M. Pinheiro and J. Reis (1997), New Estimates of Portugal’s GDP 1910-1958. Lisbon: Banco de Portugal. Beckerman, W. (1966), International Comparisons of Real Incomes, Paris: OECD Development Centre. Beckerman, W. (1993), “Is Economic Growth Still Desirable?”, in A. Szirmai, B. van Ark and D. Pilat (eds.), Explaining Economic Growth. Essays in Honour of Angus Maddison, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 77-100. Beckerman, W. and R. Bacon (1966), “International Comparisons of Income Levels: A Suggested New Measure”, Economic Journal 76 (303): 519-36. Bértola, L. (1998), El PBI de Uruguay 1870-1936 y otras estimaciones, Montevideo: Universidad de la República. 17 Bhagwati, J.N. (1984), “Why Are Services Cheaper in the Poor Countries?”. Economic Journal, 94: 279-86. Bhagwati, J.N. and B. Hansen (1973), “Should Growth Rates Be Evaluated at International Prices?”. In J.N. Bhagwati and R.S. Eckaus (Eds.), Development and Planning: Essays in Honour of Paul Rosenstein-Rodan. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Pp. 53-68. Bourguignon, F. and C. Morrisson (2002), “Inequality among World Citizens”, American Economic Review 92, 4: 727-44. Braithwaite, S.N. (1968), “Real Income Levels in Latin America”, Review of Income and Wealth 14: 113-82. Broadberry, S.N. (1994), “Comparative Productivity in British and American Manufacturing during the Nineteenth Century”, Explorations in Economic History 31: 521-48. Broadberry, S.N. (1997), “Forging Ahead, Falling Behind and Catching-up: a Sectoral Analysis of Anglo-American Productivity Differences”, Research in Economic History 17: 1-37. Broadberry, S.N. and R.R. Fremdling (1990), “Comparative Productivity in Britain and German Industry, 1907-1937”. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52, 403-421. Burger, A. (1997), “Dutch Industry in International Perspective 1850-1913”. Conference on Historical National Accounts for the Netherlands. Economic Growth and Structural Change 1800-1913. Utrecht: N.W. Posthumus Instituut. Bulmer-Thomas, V. (1994), The Economic History of Latin America since Independence, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Buyst, E. (1997), “New GNP Estimates for the Belgian Economy during the Interwar Period”. Review of Income and Wealth, 43, 357-375. CEPAL (1978), “Series históricas del crecimiento de América Latina”, Cuadernos Estadísticos de la CEPAL, Santiago de Chile: CEPAL. Coatsworth, J.H. (1993), “Notes on the Comparative Economic History of Latin America and the United States”, in W. L. Bernecker and H. W. Tobler (eds.), Development and Underdevelopment in America: Contrasts in Economic Growth in North America and Latin America in Historical Perspective, New York. Coatsworth, J. H. (1998), “Economic and Institutional Trajectories in Nineteenth- Century Latin America”, in J.H. Coatsworth and A. M. Taylor (eds.), Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 23-54. Cortés Conde, R. (1997), La economía argentina en el largo plazo (Siglos XIX y XX). Buenos Aires: Editorial Sudamericana-Universidad de San Andrés. Crafts, N. (1997), “The Human Development Index and Changes in Standards of Living: Some Historical Comparisons”, European Review of Economic History 1, 3: 299-322. Crafts, N. (2002), “The Human Development Index, 1870-1999: Some Revised Estimates”, European Review of Economic History 6, 3: 395-405. Dasgupta, P. (1990), “Well-Being and the Extent of its Realization in Poor Countries”, Economic Journal 100, 400: 1-32. 18 Dasgupta, P. (1993), An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Dasgupta, P. and M. Weale (1992), “On Measuring the Quality of Life”, World Development 20, 1: 119-31. David, P.A. (1996), “Real Income and Economic Welfare Growth in the Early Republic or, Another Try at Getting the American Story Straight”. University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History no. 5. Desai, M. (1991), “Human Development: Concept and Measurement”, European Economic Review 35: 350-7. Díaz, J. R. Lüders and G. Wagner (1998), Economía chilena 1810-1995: evolución cuantitativa del producto total y sectorial, Santiago: Pontificia Universidad Católica de Chile. Dormois, J.P. and C. Bardini (1995), “La productivité du travail dans l’industrie de divers pays d’Europe avant 1914”. Economies et Sociétés. Hitoire Quantitative de l’Economie Française. Série A F 21, 12, 77-103. Dowrick, S., Y. Dunlop and J. Quiggin (2003), “Social Indicators and Comparisons of Living Standards”, Journal of Development Economics 70: 501-529. Economic Commission for Latin America [ECLA] (1968), “The Measurement of Latin American Real Income in U.S. Dollars”, Economic Bulletin for Latin America XII, 2: 107- 41. Ehrlich, E. (1969), “Dynamic International Comparisons of National Incomes Expressed in Terms of Physical Indicators”, Osteuropa Wirtschaft 14, 1: ??. Engerman, S.L. (1997), “The Standard of Living Debate in International Perspective: Measures and Indicators”, in R.H. Steckel and R. Floud (eds.), Health and Welfare during Industrialization, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 17-45. Engerman, S. L. and K. L. Sokoloff (1997), “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies”, in S. Haber (ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind. Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800-1914, Stanford: Stanford University Press, pp. 260-304. Firestone, O.J. (1960), “Development of Canada’s Economy, 1850-1900”, in W.N. Parker (ed.), Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Studies in Income and Wealth, 24. Princeton: NBER-Princeton University Press, pp. 217-52. Flandreau, M. and C. Jobst (2004), “The international monetary system, 1890-1910. A microeconomic perspective” (mimeo). Fraile, P., R. J. Salvucci, and L. K. Salvucci (1993), “El caso cubano: exportaciones e independencia”, in L. Prados de la Escosura and S. Amaral (eds.), La independencia americana: consecuencias económicas, Madrid: Alianza, pp. 80-101. Fremdling, R.R. (1991), "Productivity Comparisons between Great Britain and Germany, 1855-1913". Scandinavian Economic History Review, 29, 28-42. 19 Goldsmith, R.W. (1986), Desenvolvimento fianceiro sob um século de inflaçao, Rio de Janeiro: Harper & Row do Brasil. Good, D.F. (1994), "The Economic Lag of Central and Eastern Europe: Income Estimates for the Habsburg Succesor States, 1870-1910". Journal of Economic History 54: 869- 91. Gormley, P.J. (1995), “The Human Development Index in 1994: Impact of Income on Country Rank”, Journal of Economic and Social Measurement 21: 253-67. Gottschalk, P. and T.M. Smelding (2000), “Empirical Evidence on Income Inequality in Industrial Countries”, in A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon (eds.), Handbook of Income Distribution, 2 vols., Amsterdam: Elsevier, I, pp. 261-307. Haber, S. (ed.) (1997), How Latin America Fell Behind. Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800-1914, Stanford: Stanford University Press. Heston, A. (1973), “A Comparison of Some Short-Cut Methods of Estimating Real Product Per Capita”, Review of Income and Wealth 19, 1: 79-104. Hicks, N. and P. Streeten (1979), “Indicators of Development: The Search for a Basic Needs Yardstick”, World Development 7: 567-80. Hobijn, B. and P.H. Franses (2001), “Are Living Standards Converging?”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 12: 171-200. Hjerppe, R. (1994), Finland's Historical National Accounts 1860-1994: Calculation Methods and Statistical Tables. Jyväskylä: J.Y.H.L. Hodne, F. and O.H. Grytten (1994), “Gross Domestic Product of Norway 1835- 1915”. Occasional Papers in Economic History, Umea University. Hoffmann, W.G. (1965), Das Wachstum der Deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19.Jahrhunderts. Berlin: Springer. Horlings, E. (1997), "The Contribution of the Service Sector to Gross Domestic Product in Belgium, 1835-1990". Universiteit Utrecht (mimeo). Hopkins, M. (1991), “Human Development Revisited: A New UNDP Report”, World Development 19, 10: 1469-73. Jaramillo Uribe, J., A. Meisel and M. Urrutia (2001), “Continuities and Discontinuities in the Fiscal and Monetary Institutions of New Granada, 1783-1850”, in M.D. Bordo and R. Cortés-Conde (eds.), Transferring Wealth and Power from the Old to the New World. Monetary and Fiscal Institutions in the 17th through the 19th Centuries, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 414-50. Isenman, P. (1980), “Inter-Country Comparison of ‘Real’ (PPP) Incomes: Revised Estimates and Unresolved Questions”. World Development 8: 61-72. Kakwani, N. (1993), “Performance in Living Standards. An International Comparison”, Journal of Development Economics 41: 307-36. 20 Kausel, A. (1979), “Österreichs Volkseinkommen 1830 bis 1913”, in Österreichisches Statistisches Zentralamt, Geschichte und Ergebnisse der zentralen amtlichen Statistik in Österreich 1829-1979. Beitraege zur öesterreichischen Statistik, Heft 550. Vienna. Kennedy, K.A. (1971), Productivity and Industrial Growth. The Irish Experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Kennedy, K.A. (1995), “The National Accounts for Ireland in the 19th and 20th Centuries”, Scandinavian Economic History Review, 43, 101-114. Kostelenos, George (1995), Money and Output in Modern Greece, 1858-1938. Athens: Centre of Planning and Economic Research (KEPE). Studies 44. Krantz, O. (1997), “Swedish Historical National Accounts 1800-1990. Aggregated Output Series”. Umea University (mimeo). Kravis, I.B. and R.E. Lipsey (1991), “The International Comparison Program: Current Status and Problems”. In P.E. Hooper and J.D. Richardson (eds.), International Economic Transactions: Issues in Measurement and Empirical Research. Studies in Income and Wealth, 55, Chicago: National Bureau Of Economic Research-University of Chicago Press. Pp. 437-464. Lains, P. (1995), A Economia portuguesa no século XIX. Crescimento económico e comércio esterno 1851-1913. Lisboa: Instituto de Ciências Sociais. Larson, D. A. and W.T. Wilford, 1979, “The Physical Quality of Life Index: A Useful Social Indicator?, World Development, 581-84. Li, H., L. Squire and H. Zou (1998), “Explaining International and Intertemporal Variations in Income Inequality”, Economic Journal 108: 26-43. Lindert, P.H. (2000), ““Three Centuries of Inequality in Britain and America,” in A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon (eds.), Handbook of Income Distribution, Amsterdam: Elsevier. Lindert, P.H. and J. G. Williamson (2003), “Does Globalization Make the World More Unequal?”, in M. D. Bordo, A. M. Taylor and J. G. Williamson (eds.), Globalization in Historical Perspective, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, chap. 5. Maddison, A. (1991), Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development. A Long-run Comparative View. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Maddison (1995), Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992, Paris: OECD Development Centre. Maddison, A. (2001), The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective, Paris: OECD Development Centre. Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD Development Centre. McGillivray, M. (1991), “The Human Development Index: Yet Another Redundant Composite Development Indicator?”, World Development 19, 10: 1461-8. 21 McGranahan, D.V., P. Pizarro, and C. Richard (1985), Measurement and Analysis of Socio-Economic Development, Geneva: United Nations Research Institute for Social Development [UNRISD]. Mitchell, B.R. (1988), Abstract of British Historical Statistics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Morris, M.D. (1979), Measuring the Condition of the World’s Poor: The Physical Quality of Life Index, New York: Pergamon. Morrisson, C. (2000), “Historical Perspectives on Income Distribution: The Case of Europe,” in A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon (eds.), Handbook of Income Distribution, Amsterdam: Elsevier. Mulhall, M.G. (1896), Industries and Wealth of Nations, London: Longmans, Green and Co.Noorbakhsh, F. (1998), “A Modified Human Development Index”, World Development 26, 3: 517-28. Newland, C. (1998), “Economic Development and Population Change: Argentina, 1810-1870”, in J. H. Coatsworth and A. M. Taylor (eds.), Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 207-22. Newland, C. and B. Poulson (1998), “Purely Animal: Pastoral Production and Early Argentine Economic Growth 1825-1865”, Explorations in Economic History, 35, 3: 325-45. North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. North, D.C., W.R. Summerhill and B.R. Weingast (2000), “Order, Disorder, and Economic Change: Latin America versus North America”, in B. Bueno de Mesquita and H. L. Root (eds.), Governing for Prosperity, New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 17-58. Nuxoll, D.A. (1994), “Differences in Relative Prices and International Differences in Growth Rates”, American Economic Review 84, 1423-36. O'Brien, P.K. and C. Keyder (1978): Economic Growth in Britain and France 1780-1914. Two Paths to the Twentieth Century. London: George Allen & Unwin. O'Brien, P.K. and L. Prados de la Escosura (1992), "Agricultural Productivity and European Industrialization, 1890-1980", Economic History Review 45, 514-36. Ó Gráda, C. (1994), Ireland. A New Economic History 1780-1939. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Ohkawa, K. and M. Shinohara (1979), Patterns of Japanese Economic Development. A Quantitative Appraisal. New Haven: Yale University Press. Ozel, I. (1997), The Economy of Turkey in the Late Ottoman and Republican Periods: A Quantitative Analysis. Unpublished M.A. Dissertation. Bogazisi University, Istanbul. Pamuk, S. (1998), “Intervention in Response to the Great Depression: Another Look at the Turkish Case, 1929-1939”, Conference on Two Centuries of Economic Change in the Mediterranean Basin. Istanbul. 22 Pinheiro, M.(ed.) (1997), Séries longas para a economia portuguesa pós II Guerra Mundial. I. Séries Estatísticas. Lisbon: Banco de Portugal. Prados de la Escosura, L. (2000), “International Comparisons of Real Product, 1820-1990: An Alternative Data Set”, Explorations in Economic History 37, 1: 1-41. Prados de la Escosura, L. (2004a), “Improving the Human Development Index: A New Data Set for Europe and the New World, 1850-2000”, Universidad Carlos III working paper. Prados de la Escosura, L. (2004b), “Colonial Independence and Economic Backwardness in Latin America”, Universidad Carlos III working paper. Prebisch, R. (1950), The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems, New York. Quiroz, A.W. (1993), “Consecuencias económicas y financieras del proceso de la independencia en el Perú, 1800-1850”, in L. Prados de la Escosura and S. Amaral (eds.), La independencia americana: consecuencias económicas, Madrid: Alianza, pp. 124-46. Ram, R. (1982), “Composite Indices Of Physical Quality of Life, Basic Needs Fulfilment, And Income. A ‘Principal Component’ Representation”, Journal of Development Economics 11: 227-47. Rankin, K. (1992), "New Zealand's Gross National Product: 1859-1939", Review of Income and Wealth. 38, 49-69. Ritschl, A. (1991), “Some National Accounts for Interwar Germany, 1925-1938” (mimeo). Ritschl, A. and M. Spoerer (1997), “Das Bruttosozialprodukt in Deutschland nach den amtlichen Volseinkommes- und Sozialproduktsstatistiken 1901-1995”. Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 2, 27-54. Salazar-Carrillo, J. (1983), “Real Product and Price Comparisons for Latin America and Other World Countries”, Economic Development and Cultural Change 31, 4: 757-73. Salazar-Carrillo, J. and I. Tirado de Alonso (1988), “Real Product and Price Comparisons between Latin America and the Rest of the World”, Review of Income and Wealth 34, 1: 27-43. Salazar-Carrillo, J. and D.S. Prasada Rao (1988), “Real Product and Price Comparisons among Latin American Countries”, in J. Salazar-Carrillo and D.S. Prasada Rao (eds.), World Comparison of Incomes, Prices and Product, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 195-205. Schulze, M.S. (1997), "Re-Estimating Austrian National Income, 1870-1913: Methods and Sources". London School of Economics Working Papers in Economic History 36/97. Sen, A.K. (1997), “Human Capital and Human Capability”, World Development 25, 12: 1959-61. 23 Singer, H.W. (1950), “The Distribution of Gains between Investing and Borrowing Countries”, American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings, 11, 2: 473-85. Smits, J.P., E. Horlings and J.L. van Zanden (1997), "The Measurement of Gross National Product and its Components. The Netherlands, 1800-1913". N.W. Posthumus Instituut Research Memorandum nr 1. Spoerer, M. (1997), “Weimar’s Investment and Growth Record in Intertemporal and International Perspective”. European Review of Economic History, 1, 271-297. Stein, S.J. and B.H. Stein (1970), The Colonial Heritage of Latin America. Essays on Economic Dependence in Perspective, New York: Oxford University Press. Srinivassan, T.N. (1994), “Human Development: A New Paradigm or Reinvention of the Wheel?”, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 84, 2: 238-43. Streeten et al. (1981), First Things First: Meeting Basic Human Needs in Developing Countries, New York: Oxford University Press. Theil, H. (1979), “World Income Inequality and its Components”, Economics Letters 2, 99-102. Theil, H. (1989), “The Development of International Inequality: 1960–1985”, Journal of Econometrics 42 (1): 145-55 Toutain, J.C. (1997), "Le produit intérieur brut de la France, 1789-1990". Economies et Societés, Histoire Economique Quantitative, Série HEQ 1, 11, 5-136. Urquhart, M.C. (1986), "New Estimates of Gross National Product, Canada, 1870- 1926: Some Implications for Canadian Development". In S.L. Engerman and R.E. Gallman (Eds.), Long-term Factors in American Economic Growth. Studies in Income and Wealth, 51. Chicago: NBER-University of Chicago Press. Pp. 9-94. United Nations Development Program [UNDP] (1990, 1993, 2001), Human Development Report, New York: Oxford University Press. Ward, M. and J. Devereux (2003a), “Measuring British Decline: Direct versus Long Span Measures”, Journal of Economic History 63: 826-51. Ward, M. and J. Devereux (2003b), “New Evidence on Catch-Up and Convergence after 1870” (mimeo). Williamson, J.G. (1995), “The Evolution of Global Labour Markets since 1830: Background Evidence and Hypotheses”, Explorations in Economic History 32, 141-96. Williamson, J.G. (1996), "Globalization, Convergence, and History”, Journal of Economic History 56, 277-306. Williamson, J.G. (1997), “Globalization and Inequality, Past and Present”, World Bank Economic Observer 12, 2: 117-35. 24 Appendix A Countries included in ‘OECD’ and Latin America’s GDP sample since 1870. Australia (Core) Austria (Periphery) Belgium (Core) Canada (Core) Denmark (Core) Finland (Periphery) France (Core) Germany (Core) Greece (Periphery) Ireland (since 1913) (Periphery) Italy (Periphery) Japan (Periphery) Netherlands (Core) New Zealand (Core) Norway (Core) Portugal (Periphery) Spain (Periphery) Sweden (Core) Switzerland (Core) Turkey (since 1913) (Periphery) UK (Core) USA (Core) Argentina (Periphery) Bolivia (since 1950) (Periphery) Brazil (Periphery) Chile (Periphery) Colombia (since 1913) (Periphery) Costa Rica (since 1929) (Periphery) Dom. Rep. (since 1950) (Periphery) Ecuador (since 1950) (Periphery) El Salvador (since 1929) (Periphery) Guatemala (since 1929) (Periphery) Haití (since 1950) (Periphery) Honduras (since 1929) (Periphery) México (Periphery) Nicaragua (since 1929) (Periphery) Panama (since 1950) (Periphery) Paraguay (since 1950) (Periphery) Peru (since 1913) (Periphery) Uruguay (Periphery) Venezuela (Periphery) 25 Appendix B Countries included in ‘OECD’ and Latin America’s HDI sample since 1890. Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland (since 1913) Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey (since 1913) UK USA Argentina Bolivia (since 1950) Brazil Chile (since 1900) Colombia (since 1913) Costa Rica (since 1929) Dom. Rep. (since 1950) Ecuador (since 1950) El Salvador (since 1929) Guatemala (since 1929) Haití (since 1950) Honduras (since 1929) Mexico Nicaragua (since 1929) Panama (since 1950) Paraguay (since 1950) Peru (since 1950) Uruguay (since 1900) Venezuela (since 1900) 26 Appendix C Sources for GDP per Capita Volume Indices for ‘OECD’ and Latin America GDP volume or quantity indices for OECD countries come from the national sources stated below or from Maddison (2003). Population figures are taken mainly from Maddison (2003), Mitchell (1992, 1993, 1994), and the League of Nations and UN Yearbooks, unless stated in the national sources below. Data on Latin American GDP and population in the twentieth century are provided by P. Astorga, A. R. Bergés, and E.V.K. FitzGerald (2004), The Oxford Latin American Economic History Database (OxLAD), The Latin American Centre, Oxford University, http://oxlad.thedesignfly.net/ Argentina. Cortés Conde (1997) for 1875-1935. I estimated the level for 1870 by backward projection of the 1875 level assuming the rate of growth for 1870-1875 was identical to that of 1875-1880. Austria. Imperial (Habsburg) Austria: 1830-1870, Kausel (1979); 1870-1913, Schulze (1997). Modern (Republic of) Austria's level for 1913 was derived by applying Good´s (1994) ratio (1.346) to Schulze’s Imperial estimates. Belgium. 1830-1913, Horlings (1997); 1925-1938, average of GDP estimates from Buyst (1997) (income and expenditure approaches) and Horlings (1997) (output). Brazil. 1850-1980, Goldsmith (1986). Canada. 1850-1860, Firestone (1960); 1870-1926, Urquhart (1986). Although Urquhart seems to favor GNP, GDP was preferred to GNP here. Chile. 1820-1990, Díaz, Lüders and Wagner (1998). France. 1830-1990, Toutain (1997). Finland. 1860-1990, Hjerppe (1994). Germany. 1850-1900, Hoffmann (1965); 1900-1950, Spoerer (1997) and Ritschl and Spoerer (1997). 1850-1900, GNP at market prices was obtained by re-scalating NNP with the GNP/NNP ratio for 1901-13, from Spoerer (1997). 1850-1913, GDP at market prices was computed from the GNP estimates and from data on net factor payments abroad taken from Hoffmann (1965) and Ritschl (1991). West Germany figures since 1950 include the Saar and West Berlin and figures for West Germany in 1950-55 had to be re-scaled by 8.6 per cent. Greece. 1860-1938, Kostelenos (1995). Ireland. 1913, computed by applying the Republic of Ireland/Ireland ratio in Kennedy (1995, Table 2) to Ó Gráda´s (1994) estimates for all Ireland. Republic of Ireland, Kennedy (1971) for 1929-1960. Japan. 1890-1938, Ohkawa and Shinohara (1979). Netherlands. 1870-1913, Smits, Horlings and van Zanden (1997), average of expenditure, income, and output estimates; 1925-1938, den Bakker, Huitker and van Bochove (1990). Norway. 1835-1913, Hodne and Grytten (1994). New Zealand. Rankin (1992), 1870-1938. Portugal. 1870-1910, Lains (1995); 1910-1955, Batista, Martins, Pinheiro and Reis (1997); 1955-1990, Pinheiro (1997). Spain. Prados de la Escosura (2003), 1850-1990. Sweden. Krantz (1997), 1820-1990. Turkey. 1913-1938, Private communications by Sevket Pamuk which derive from Ozel (1997), and Pamuk (1998). United Kingdom. 1830-1990, Mitchell (1988). USA. 1820-1860, David (1996), “narrow” estimates at constant prices, which coincides with Weiss (1994) “conventional estimate” for 1840-1860. 1870-1929, Balke and Gordon (1989). Uruguay. Bértola (1998), 1870-1929. Venezuela. Baptista (1997), 1830-1990. 27 Graph 1. Real GDP per Capita in OECD and Latin America, 1850-1990 (1960 US Relative Prices) 1 10 100 1000 10000 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 semilog scale LA3 LA6 LA8 LA13 LA19 OECD13 OECD20 OECD22 28 Graph 2A. Relative Real GDP per Capita in Latin America, 1850-1990 (OECD = 1) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,00 0,05 0,10 0,15 0,20 0,25 0,30 0,35 0,40 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 RYLA3 RYLA6 RYLA8 RYLA13 RYLA19 29 Graph 2B. Relative Real GDP per Capita in Latin America, 1850-1990 (Anglo New World = 1) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,00 0,05 0,10 0,15 0,20 0,25 0,30 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 RYLA3 RYLA6 RYLA8 RYLA13 RYLA19 30 Graph 3. Real GDP per Capita in Eight Latin American Countries (1960 US Relative Prices) 1 10 100 1000 10000 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 semilog scale Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Uruguay Venezuela LA6 LA8 31 Graph 4. Relative Real GDP per Capita in Eight Latin American Countries (OECD = 1) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,00 0,20 0,40 0,60 0,80 1,00 1,20 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Uruguay Venezuela LA 32 Graph 5. Per Capita Income Inequality in Latin America and OECD (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,000 0,050 0,100 0,150 0,200 0,250 0,300 0,350 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 MLD1870 MLD1913 MLD1929 MLD1950 Theil1870 Theil1913 Theil1929 Theil1950 33 Graph 6A. Within-regions and Between-regions Income Inequality in OECD and Latin America (MLD) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,000 0,050 0,100 0,150 0,200 0,250 0,300 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 within1870 within1913 within1929 within1950 between1870 between1913 between1929 between1950 34 Graph 6B. Within-regions and Between-regions Income Inequality in OECD and Latin America (Theil) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,000 0,020 0,040 0,060 0,080 0,100 0,120 0,140 0,160 0,180 0,200 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 within1870 within1913 within1929 within1950 between1870 between1913 between1929 between1950 35 Graph 7A. Income Inequality within OECD and Latin America (MLD) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,000 0,050 0,100 0,150 0,200 0,250 0,300 0,350 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 OECD20 LA6 OECD22 LA8 LA13 LA19 36 Graph 7B. Income Inequality within OECD and Latin America (Theil) (1960 US Relative Prices) 0,000 0,050 0,100 0,150 0,200 0,250 0,300 0,350 1870 1880 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 OECD20 LA6 OECD22 LA8 LA13 LA19 37 Graph 8. HDI in OECD and Latin America 0,010 0,100 1,000 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 semilog scale LA3 LA6 LA12 LA19 OECD19 OECD21 OECD22 38 Graph 9. Relative HDI in Latin America (OECD = 1) 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 RLA3 RLA6 RLA12 RLA19 39 Graph 10. HDI in Eight Latin American Countries 0,010 0,100 1,000 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 semilog scale Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Uruguay Venezuela 40 Graph 11. Relative HDI in Eight Latin American Countries (OECD = 1) 0,00 0,10 0,20 0,30 0,40 0,50 0,60 0,70 0,80 0,90 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Uruguay Venezuela 41 Graph 12. HDI Inequality in OECD and Latin America 0,000 0,010 0,020 0,030 0,040 0,050 0,060 0,070 0,080 0,090 0,100 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 MLD1890 MLD1900 MLD1913 MLD1929 Theil1890 Theil1900 Theil1913 Theil1929 42 Graph 13A. Within-regions and Between-regions HDI Inequality in OECD and Latin America (MLD) 0,000 0,010 0,020 0,030 0,040 0,050 0,060 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 within1890 within1900 within1913 within1929 between1890 between1900 between1913 between1929 43 Graph 13B. Within-Regions and Between-regions HDI Inequality in OECD and Latin America (Theil) 0,000 0,010 0,020 0,030 0,040 0,050 0,060 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 within1890 within1900 within1913 within1929 between1890 between1900 between1913 between1929 44 Graph 14A. HDI Inequality within OECD and Latin America (MLD) 0,000 0,010 0,020 0,030 0,040 0,050 0,060 0,070 0,080 0,090 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 OECD19 OECD21 LA3 LA6 LA7 LA12 45 Graph 14B. HDI Inequality within OECD and Latin America (Theil) 0,000 0,020 0,040 0,060 0,080 0,100 0,120 0,140 1890 1900 1913 1929 1938 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 OECD19 OECD21 LA3 LA6 LA7 LA12 46 Table 1 (a) Decomposing Inequality in OECD and Latin America, 1870--1990 (Estimated with Real GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1870 0,106 0,066 0,094 0,9186 0,0814 0,068 0,038 0,094 0,066 0,106 0,9735 0,0265 0,067 0,027 1880 0,112 0,064 0,104 0,9122 0,0878 0,068 0,044 0,094 0,062 0,110 0,9726 0,0274 0,064 0,030 1890 0,104 0,055 0,156 0,9074 0,0926 0,064 0,040 0,084 0,052 0,168 0,9683 0,0317 0,056 0,029 1900 0,117 0,052 0,251 0,8987 0,1013 0,072 0,045 0,087 0,048 0,237 0,9657 0,0343 0,055 0,032 1913 0,125 0,055 0,316 0,8900 0,1100 0,083 0,042 0,091 0,050 0,292 0,9587 0,0413 0,060 0,031 1929 0,133 0,055 0,261 0,8700 0,1300 0,082 0,050 0,099 0,052 0,259 0,9516 0,0484 0,062 0,037 1938 0,119 0,039 0,213 0,8614 0,1386 0,063 0,057 0,087 0,036 0,214 0,9498 0,0502 0,045 0,042 1950 0,221 0,138 0,194 0,8322 0,1678 0,148 0,074 0,186 0,128 0,194 0,9412 0,0588 0,132 0,054 1960 0,175 0,063 0,138 0,8095 0,1905 0,078 0,098 0,135 0,060 0,138 0,9395 0,0605 0,065 0,071 1970 0,183 0,023 0,128 0,7808 0,2192 0,046 0,137 0,124 0,022 0,128 0,9393 0,0607 0,029 0,096 1980 0,175 0,017 0,061 0,7464 0,2536 0,028 0,147 0,126 0,017 0,062 0,9242 0,0758 0,020 0,106 1990 0,249 0,019 0,051 0,7244 0,2756 0,028 0,221 0,169 0,018 0,051 0,9372 0,0628 0,020 0,149 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1870-1913 -0,0038 0,0044 -0,0282 -0,0047 -0,0021 0,0008 0,0065 -0,0235 0,0026 -0,0033 1880-1913 -0,0034 0,0050 -0,0337 -0,0062 0,0015 0,0012 0,0069 -0,0297 0,0020 -0,0004 1913-1938 0,0036 0,0153 0,0158 0,0129 -0,0101 0,0033 0,0140 0,0125 0,0126 -0,0099 1950-1990 -0,0029 0,0501 0,0335 0,0420 -0,0275 0,0025 0,0490 0,0336 0,0470 -0,0252 1870-1990 -0,0071 0,0105 0,0051 0,0076 -0,0147 -0,0049 0,0108 0,0062 0,0100 -0,0143 1880-1990 -0,0073 0,0113 0,0065 0,0082 -0,0147 -0,0053 0,0113 0,0070 0,0105 -0,0144 47 Table 1 (b) Decomposing Inequality in OECD and Latin America, 1913--1990 (Estimated with Real GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1913 0,141 0,059 0,291 0,8722 0,1278 0,089 0,052 0,103 0,054 0,284 0,954 0,046 0,065 0,038 1929 0,145 0,059 0,235 0,8544 0,1456 0,085 0,060 0,110 0,056 0,244 0,947 0,053 0,066 0,044 1938 0,129 0,041 0,187 0,8451 0,1549 0,064 0,065 0,096 0,039 0,194 0,945 0,055 0,047 0,048 1950 0,232 0,144 0,173 0,8146 0,1854 0,150 0,083 0,199 0,134 0,179 0,935 0,065 0,137 0,061 1960 0,193 0,074 0,124 0,7912 0,2088 0,084 0,108 0,152 0,069 0,129 0,934 0,066 0,073 0,079 1970 0,208 0,040 0,116 0,7613 0,2387 0,058 0,150 0,147 0,036 0,121 0,934 0,066 0,041 0,105 1980 0,203 0,038 0,063 0,7276 0,2724 0,045 0,158 0,150 0,032 0,066 0,918 0,082 0,035 0,115 1990 0,280 0,040 0,060 0,7055 0,2945 0,046 0,234 0,196 0,035 0,058 0,932 0,068 0,036 0,159 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1913-1938 0,0036 0,0145 0,0177 0,0132 -0,0088 0,0031 0,0134 0,0152 0,0125 -0,0090 1950-1990 -0,0047 0,0321 0,0264 0,0295 -0,0260 0,0004 0,0340 0,0281 0,0334 -0,0239 1913-1990 -0,0089 0,0051 0,0205 0,0086 -0,0195 -0,0083 0,0059 0,0206 0,0076 -0,0185 48 Table 1 (c) Decomposing Inequality in OECD and Latin America, 1929--1990 (Estimated with Real GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1929 0,149 0,059 0,225 0,8467 0,1533 0,085 0,065 0,113 0,056 0,237 0,945 0,055 0,066 0,048 1938 0,134 0,041 0,182 0,8369 0,1631 0,064 0,070 0,099 0,039 0,192 0,942 0,058 0,048 0,052 1950 0,238 0,144 0,169 0,8053 0,1947 0,149 0,089 0,203 0,134 0,177 0,933 0,067 0,137 0,066 1960 0,201 0,074 0,125 0,7808 0,2192 0,085 0,117 0,158 0,069 0,130 0,931 0,069 0,073 0,084 1970 0,220 0,040 0,117 0,7493 0,2507 0,060 0,160 0,155 0,036 0,123 0,931 0,069 0,042 0,113 1980 0,219 0,038 0,074 0,7142 0,2858 0,048 0,171 0,160 0,032 0,074 0,915 0,085 0,036 0,124 1990 0,303 0,040 0,075 0,6905 0,3095 0,051 0,252 0,209 0,035 0,070 0,929 0,071 0,037 0,172 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1929-1950 -0,0223 -0,0423 0,0137 -0,0269 -0,0154 -0,0278 -0,0420 0,0140 -0,0351 -0,0154 1950-1990 -0,0060 0,0321 0,0202 0,0269 -0,0260 -0,0007 0,0340 0,0232 0,0328 -0,0240 1929-1990 -0,0116 0,0065 0,0180 0,0084 -0,0223 -0,0100 0,0078 0,0200 0,0094 -0,0210 49 Table 1 (d) Decomposing Inequality in OECD and Latin America, 1950--1990 (Estimated with Real GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1950 0,251 0,144 0,171 0,7894 0,2106 0,150 0,101 0,212 0,134 0,180 0,929 0,071 0,138 0,074 1960 0,219 0,074 0,135 0,7643 0,2357 0,088 0,131 0,169 0,069 0,139 0,928 0,072 0,074 0,095 1970 0,243 0,040 0,132 0,7320 0,2680 0,065 0,178 0,168 0,036 0,133 0,928 0,072 0,043 0,125 1980 0,241 0,038 0,089 0,6955 0,3045 0,053 0,187 0,174 0,032 0,084 0,911 0,089 0,037 0,137 1990 0,332 0,040 0,092 0,6701 0,3299 0,057 0,275 0,226 0,035 0,081 0,926 0,074 0,038 0,188 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1950-1990 -0,0070 0,0321 0,0154 0,0241 -0,0250 -0,0016 0,0340 0,0200 0,0322 -0,0232 50 Table 2 Assessing the Impact of Differences in Population and per capita GDP Growth in OECD and Latin America Income Inequality: Annual Rates of Inequality Reductio (Weighted Inequality Measured with Real GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices Counterfactual Zero Variance in Counterfactual Zero Variance in Population per capita GDP Population per capita GDP Actual Value Growth Growth Actual Value Growth Growth 1870-1913 -0,0038 -0,0107 -0,0023 1880-1913 -0,0034 -0,0106 -0,0021 1913-1938 0,0036 0,0124 -0,0061 0,0036 0,0122 -0,0061 1913-1950 -0,0142 -0,0143 -0,0082 -0,0135 -0,0127 -0,0080 1950-1990 -0,0029 0,0159 -0,0061 -0,0047 0,0147 -0,0057 Theil Indices Counterfactual Zero Variance in Counterfactual Zero Variance in Population per capita GDP Population per capita GDP Actual Value Growth Growth Actual Value Growth Growth 1870-1913 0,0008 -0,0129 -0,0016 1880-1913 0,0012 -0,0130 -0,0014 1913-1938 0,0033 0,0076 -0,0054 0,0031 0,0072 -0,0055 1913-1950 -0,0183 -0,0222 -0,0077 -0,0176 -0,0207 -0,0076 1950-1990 0,0025 0,0157 -0,0056 0,0004 0,0153 -0,0057 51 Table 3 (a) Decomposing Inequality of Human Development in OECD and Latin America, 1890--1990 (Human Development estimated with GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1890 0,082 0,044 0,040 0,9199 0,0801 0,043 0,039 0,082 0,033 0,094 0,9199 0,0801 0,038 0,044 1900 0,076 0,037 0,048 0,9113 0,0887 0,038 0,038 0,079 0,025 0,123 0,9113 0,0887 0,034 0,046 1913 0,066 0,027 0,060 0,9022 0,0978 0,031 0,036 0,067 0,021 0,106 0,9022 0,0978 0,030 0,037 1929 0,064 0,019 0,076 0,8826 0,1174 0,025 0,039 0,075 0,028 0,114 0,8826 0,1174 0,038 0,038 1938 0,061 0,017 0,068 0,8741 0,1259 0,023 0,038 0,078 0,035 0,088 0,8741 0,1259 0,042 0,037 1950 0,057 0,014 0,056 0,8466 0,1534 0,020 0,037 0,061 0,018 0,058 0,8466 0,1534 0,024 0,037 1960 0,041 0,006 0,027 0,8255 0,1745 0,010 0,031 0,027 0,003 0,014 0,8255 0,1745 0,005 0,022 1970 0,040 0,004 0,019 0,7979 0,2021 0,007 0,033 0,024 0,002 0,009 0,7979 0,2021 0,003 0,022 1980 0,034 0,002 0,011 0,7653 0,2347 0,005 0,029 0,027 0,003 0,008 0,7653 0,2347 0,005 0,022 1990 0,035 0,002 0,011 0,7451 0,2549 0,005 0,030 0,040 0,012 0,010 0,7451 0,2549 0,012 0,029 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1890-1913 0,0094 0,0205 -0,0174 0,0154 0,0035 0,0089 0,0188 -0,0055 0,0105 0,0075 1900-1913 0,0104 0,0230 -0,0171 0,0165 0,0048 0,0132 0,0123 0,0112 0,0099 0,0158 1913-1938 0,0002 0,0196 0,0014 0,0126 -0,0099 -0,0180 -0,0243 0,0013 -0,0181 -0,0179 1950-1990 0,0121 0,0436 0,0406 0,0370 0,0046 0,0104 0,0101 0,0436 0,0184 0,0063 1890-1990 0,0085 0,0290 0,0129 0,0224 0,0025 0,0071 0,0100 0,0223 0,0118 0,0043 1900-1990 0,0086 0,0304 0,0163 0,0234 0,0025 0,0075 0,0081 0,0278 0,0119 0,0051 1913-1990 0,0073 0,0317 0,0241 0,0252 -0,0003 0,0028 0,0059 0,0285 0,0107 -0,0026 52 Table 3 (b) Decomposing Inequality of Human Development in OECD and Latin America, 1900--1990 (Human Development estimated with GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1900 0,072 0,037 0,056 0,9040 0,0960 0,039 0,034 0,077 0,025 0,130 0,9040 0,0960 0,035 0,042 1913 0,063 0,027 0,065 0,8948 0,1052 0,031 0,032 0,065 0,021 0,102 0,8948 0,1052 0,030 0,035 1929 0,061 0,019 0,077 0,8743 0,1257 0,026 0,035 0,073 0,027 0,090 0,8743 0,1257 0,035 0,038 1938 0,058 0,017 0,069 0,8657 0,1343 0,024 0,034 0,076 0,035 0,078 0,8657 0,1343 0,041 0,035 1950 0,053 0,014 0,058 0,8380 0,1620 0,021 0,032 0,058 0,018 0,064 0,8380 0,1620 0,025 0,033 1960 0,036 0,006 0,028 0,8173 0,1827 0,010 0,026 0,024 0,003 0,020 0,8173 0,1827 0,006 0,018 1970 0,035 0,004 0,020 0,7906 0,2094 0,007 0,028 0,022 0,002 0,019 0,7906 0,2094 0,005 0,017 1980 0,028 0,002 0,012 0,7594 0,2406 0,005 0,023 0,022 0,003 0,015 0,7594 0,2406 0,006 0,016 1990 0,028 0,002 0,012 0,7401 0,2599 0,005 0,023 0,034 0,012 0,019 0,7401 0,2599 0,014 0,020 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1900-1913 0,0104 0,0228 -0,0108 0,0163 0,0042 0,0126 0,0120 0,0184 0,0123 0,0128 1913-1938 0,0001 0,0198 0,0020 0,0125 -0,0117 -0,0180 -0,0243 0,0009 -0,0183 -0,0178 1950-1990 0,0157 0,0437 0,0387 0,0358 0,0079 0,0134 0,0101 0,0308 0,0154 0,0120 1900-1990 0,0105 0,0304 0,0168 0,0228 0,0042 0,0091 0,0081 0,0216 0,0104 0,0081 1913-1990 0,0094 0,0318 0,0229 0,0244 0,0013 0,0046 0,0059 0,0190 0,0081 0,0015 53 Table 3 (c) Decomposing Inequality of Human Development in OECD and Latin America, 1913--1990 (Human Development estimated with GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1913 0,068 0,029 0,067 0,8757 0,1243 0,033 0,034 0,058 0,019 0,096 0,8757 0,1243 0,029 0,030 1929 0,071 0,020 0,069 0,8593 0,1407 0,027 0,044 0,086 0,028 0,105 0,8593 0,1407 0,038 0,047 1938 0,067 0,018 0,061 0,8497 0,1503 0,024 0,043 0,086 0,034 0,083 0,8497 0,1503 0,042 0,044 1950 0,060 0,014 0,050 0,8186 0,1814 0,021 0,039 0,064 0,018 0,054 0,8186 0,1814 0,024 0,040 1960 0,044 0,006 0,024 0,7940 0,2060 0,010 0,034 0,030 0,003 0,014 0,7940 0,2060 0,005 0,024 1970 0,042 0,004 0,017 0,7635 0,2365 0,007 0,035 0,026 0,002 0,009 0,7635 0,2365 0,003 0,023 1980 0,036 0,003 0,010 0,7281 0,2719 0,005 0,031 0,028 0,003 0,008 0,7281 0,2719 0,005 0,023 1990 0,036 0,002 0,011 0,7042 0,2958 0,005 0,031 0,041 0,012 0,011 0,7042 0,2958 0,012 0,029 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1913-1938 0,0006 0,0195 0,0040 0,0131 -0,0087 -0,0154 -0,0230 0,0056 -0,0147 -0,0161 1950-1990 0,0127 0,0437 0,0391 0,0364 0,0057 0,0113 0,0099 0,0405 0,0186 0,0078 1913-1990 0,0082 0,0318 0,0240 0,0251 0,0012 0,0047 0,0063 0,0285 0,0119 0,0002 54 Table 3 (d) Decomposing Inequality of Human Development in OECD and Latin America, 1929--1990 (Human Development estimated with GDP per head at 1960 US relative prices) MLD Indices within- between- Theil Indices within- between- Population Shares regions regions GDP Shares GDP Shares regions regions OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality OECD & OECD Latin America OECD Latin America Inequality Inequality Latin America Latin America Panel A. Levels of Inequality 1929 0,076 0,020 0,074 0,8513 0,1487 0,028 0,048 0,093 0,028 0,119 0,8513 0,1487 0,041 0,052 1938 0,072 0,018 0,064 0,8412 0,1588 0,025 0,047 0,092 0,034 0,089 0,8412 0,1588 0,043 0,049 1950 0,065 0,014 0,053 0,8089 0,1911 0,022 0,043 0,069 0,018 0,057 0,8089 0,1911 0,025 0,044 1960 0,048 0,006 0,028 0,7830 0,2170 0,011 0,037 0,034 0,003 0,019 0,7830 0,2170 0,006 0,027 1970 0,046 0,004 0,020 0,7508 0,2492 0,008 0,038 0,029 0,002 0,012 0,7508 0,2492 0,004 0,025 1980 0,040 0,003 0,014 0,7138 0,2862 0,006 0,034 0,031 0,003 0,011 0,7138 0,2862 0,006 0,025 1990 0,041 0,002 0,014 0,6883 0,3117 0,006 0,034 0,043 0,012 0,013 0,6883 0,3117 0,012 0,031 Panel B. Annual Rates of Inequality Reduction 1929-1950 0,0077 0,0156 0,0155 0,0118 0,0055 0,0145 0,0212 0,0348 0,0233 0,0086 1950-1990 0,0117 0,0437 0,0328 0,0314 0,0056 0,0116 0,0099 0,0379 0,0184 0,0084 1929-1990 0,0103 0,0340 0,0268 0,0246 0,0056 0,0126 0,0138 0,0368 0,0201 0,0085 copyright autor do texto

Nenhum comentário:

Postar um comentário

Contador de visitas